专栏名称: 唧唧堂
唧唧堂学术管理分享平台,更好的学术阅读与写作!
目录
相关文章推荐
甘肃省司法厅  ·  夜读|真正有本事的人,往往都有这4个特征 ·  昨天  
冯唐  ·  冯唐五年前提出了一个好问题 ·  4 天前  
CEO盈利思维  ·  聪明与智慧的区别!(看完醒悟) ·  3 天前  
51好读  ›  专栏  ›  唧唧堂

唧唧堂:RES 经济学研究评论2021年3月刊论文摘要14篇

唧唧堂  · 公众号  ·  · 2021-05-12 12:42

正文

picture from Internet
解析作者 | 唧唧堂经济金融学写作小组: ALLY
审校 | 唧唧堂管理学写作小组: Eric J, 明 月奴
编辑 | 悠悠



1、稳健的交易机制设计


摘要:在这篇文章中,我们为具有私人信息和相互依赖价值的交换经济设计了交易机制,这些机制在事后个体理性,激励相容,产生预算盈余以及事后几乎有效的情况下,与许多代理人息息相关。我们的框架是完全没有先验的,并且我们也没有设置对称限制。该机制可以在不考虑信息结构或效用函数的情况下,通过一种新颖的、具有歧视性条件的双重拍卖来实现。我们也证明了没有其他机制满足约束条件会产生低效率的小额订单。


Abstract: In this article, we provide mechanisms for exchange economies with private information and interdependent values, which are ex post individually rational, incentive compatible, generate budget surplus, and are ex post nearly efficient, with many agents. Our framework is entirely prior-free, and we make no symmetry restrictions. The mechanisms can be implemented using a novel discriminatory conditional double auction, without knowledge of information structure or utility functions. We also show that no other mechanism satisfying the constraints can generate inefficiency of smaller order.


参考文献:Pasha Andreyanov, Tomasz Sadzik(2021). Robust Mechanism Design of Exchange. The Review of Economic Studies,88(2),521–573.



2、组织中的面对面交流


摘要:沟通是组织中不可或缺的一部分,然而关于沟通与员工生产效率之间关系的实地证据仍然比较稀缺。我们认为沟通的核心作用是传递信息,从而帮助同事更好地完成他们的工作。我们建立了一个简单的模型,在该模型中,员工通过权衡其收益以及与发送者所花费的时间成本来选择通信量,并根据这种权衡结果来得出一组经验预测。然后,我们在一个组织中进行了自然实验,当该组织出现问题时,这些问题必须由两个员工依次处理。由于存在外部原因,第一个员工有时可以和他们的同事面对面交流。与我们模型预测的结果一致,我们发现:(1)当可以进行面对面交流时,以第一个员工花费更少时间处理传入问题为代价,第二个员工会工作得更快,(2)对于同质且位置相近的团队而言,当第二个员工更忙时,这种效应会更明显,(3)员工激励机制决定了他们与同事进行沟通交流的程度。我们还发现,员工在他们的沟通决策中会将部分社会结果内部化。我们的研究解释了团队中的员工如何根据成本和收益调整相互沟通的数量。


Abstract: Communication is integral to organizations and yet field evidence on the relation between communication and worker productivity remains scarce. We argue that a core role of communication is to transmit information that helps co-workers do their job better. We build a simple model in which workers choose the amount of communication by trading off this benefit against the time cost incurred by the sender, and use it to derive a set of empirical predictions. We then exploit a natural experiment in an organization where problems arrive and must be sequentially dealt with by two workers. For exogenous reasons, the first worker can sometimes communicate face-to-face with their colleague. Consistently with the predictions of our model, we find that: (1) the second worker works faster (at the cost of the first worker having less time to deal with incoming problems) when face-to-face communication is possible, (2) this effect is stronger when the second worker is busier and for homogenous and closely located teams, and (3) the (career) incentives of workers determine how much they communicate with their colleagues. We also find that workers partially internalise social outcomes in their communication decisions. Our findings illustrate how workers in teams adjust the amount of mutual communication to its costs and benefits.


参考文献:Diego Battiston, Jordi Blanes i Vidal, Tom Kirchmaier(2021). Face-to-Face Communication in Organizations. The Review of Economic Studies,88(2),574-609.



3、自我执行协议和正向演绎推理


摘要:在动态游戏中,玩家可能会在游戏结束前观察与赛前预先约定的、可能不完整的、不具约束力的协议偏差。将偏差合理化的尝试可能会导致玩家在后续游戏过程中改变他们对偏差者行为的看法。这种正向演绎推理的实例不仅是以合理性的互动信念为基础,还要遵守协议本身。我研究了这种合理化的互动信念对自我执行协议的影响。因此,通过某种协议,游戏的结果被认为是可以实现的。该结论本质上与传统的均衡改进建议大相径庭。一个非子博弈的完美均衡结果可能是由自我执行协议引起的,而一个子博弈的完美均衡结果则可能不是由自我执行协议引起的。协议的不完整性对于最终执行的结果至关重要。


Abstract: In dynamic games, players may observe a deviation from a pre-play, possibly incomplete, non-binding agreement before the game is over. The attempt to rationalize the deviation may lead players to revise their beliefs about the deviator’s behaviour in the continuation of the game. This instance of forward induction reasoning is based on interactive beliefs about not just rationality, but also the compliance with the agreement itself. I study the effects of such rationalization on the self-enforceability of the agreement. Accordingly, outcomes of the game are deemed implementable by some agreement or not. Conclusions depart substantially from what the traditional equilibrium refinements suggest. A non-subgame perfect equilibrium outcome may be induced by a self-enforcing agreement, while a subgame perfect equilibrium outcome may not. The incompleteness of the agreement can be crucial to implement an outcome.


参考文献:Emiliano Catonini(2021). Self-enforcing Agreements and Forward Induction Reasoning. The Review of Economic Studies,88(2),610-642.


picture from Internet


4、贸易和国内生产网络


摘要:我们研究了有多少以及哪些类型的公司最终会依赖国外投入,向国外市场销售产品,并受到贸易冲击的影响。为了掌握公司可以通过向进口或出口的国内公司进行买卖来实现间接交易的信息。我们使用了比利时有关国内公司与公司之间销售以及外贸交易信息的数据。我们发现,大多数公司使用了大量的国外投入,但只有少数公司通过直接进口表现出这种依赖性。虽然直接出口商很少,但大多数公司都是间接出口。但是,在大多数公司中,间接出口数量有限,而国内销售是主要的收入来源。我们证明,国外需求冲击对公司收入的传导影响是来源于公司最终向国外市场销售的数量,而不是因为这些销售是来自直接或间接出口。


Abstract: We examine how many and what kind of firms ultimately rely on foreign inputs, sell to foreign markets, and are affected by trade shocks. To capture that firms can trade indirectly by buying from or selling to domestic firms that import or export, we use Belgian data with information on both domestic firm-to-firm sales and foreign trade transactions. We find that most firms use a lot of foreign inputs, but only a small number of firms show that dependence through direct imports. While direct exporters are rare, a majority of firms are indirectly exporting. In most firms, however, indirect export is quantitatively modest, and sales at home are the key source of revenue. We show that what matters for the transmission of foreign demand shocks to a firm’s revenue is how much the firm ultimately sells to foreign markets, not whether these sales are from direct or indirect export.


参考文献:Emmanuel Dhyne, Ayumu Ken Kikkawa, Magne Mogstad, Felix Tintelnot(2021). Trade and Domestic Production Networks. The Review of Economic Studies,88(2),643-668.



5、住房财富效应:基于长远视角


摘要:追溯到20世纪80年代,我们针对住房财富效应提供了一种新的随时间变化的估计。我们使用了三种识别策略:具有丰富控件集的普通最小二乘法,塞兹住房供给弹性工具,以及一种利用城市在区域房价周期中存在系统性差异的新工具。所有这三种识别策略均表明,在21世纪初,住房财富弹性要比先前时期小。这意味着,价格波动较大是住房在21世纪初的繁荣与萧条中发挥重要作用的主要原因,而不是由消费对房价的敏感性增加所致。尽管它们在经济上仍然很重要,但是基于我们采用的新工具进行全样本估计,所估计的结果要比最近估计的结果小。我们没有发现明显的证据来证明住房财富弹性的繁荣与萧条不对称。我们认为,这些实证结果与具有借贷约束,不可信任的收入风险,非流动性风险和长期抵押贷款的标准生命周期模型中的住房财富弹性行为是一致的。在我们的模型中,住房财富弹性变化对贷款价值分布的影响相对不敏感,主要有以下两个原因:第一,低杠杆房主在住房财富弹性中占相当大的比例;第二,贷款价值分布的右移不仅增加了高度敏感的、受约束的代理人数量,而且也增加了消费对房价不敏感的潜在代理人数量。


Abstract: We provide new time-varying estimates of the housing wealth effect back to the 1980s. We use three identification strategies: ordinary least squares with a rich set of controls, the Saiz housing supply elasticity instrument, and a new instrument that exploits systematic differences in city-level exposure to regional house price cycles. All three identification strategies indicate that housing wealth elasticities were if anything slightly smaller in the 2000s than in earlier time periods. This implies that the important role housing played in the boom and bust of the 2000s was due to larger price movements rather than an increase in the sensitivity of consumption to house prices. Full-sample estimates based on our new instrument are smaller than recent estimates, though they remain economically important. We find no significant evidence of a boom–bust asymmetry in the housing wealth elasticity. We show that these empirical results are consistent with the behaviour of the housing wealth elasticity in a standard life-cycle model with borrowing constraints, uninsurable income risk, illiquid housing, and long-term mortgages. In our model, the housing wealth elasticity is relatively insensitive to changes in the distribution of loan-to-value (LTV) for two reasons: first, low-leverage homeowners account for a substantial and stable part of the aggregate housing wealth elasticity; second, a rightward shift in the LTV distribution increases not only the number of highly sensitive constrained agents but also the number of underwater agents whose consumption is insensitive to house prices.


参考文献:Adam M Guren, Alisdair McKay, Emi Nakamura, Jón Steinsson(2021). Housing Wealth Effects: The Long View.The Review of Economic Studies,88(2),669-707.



6、浏览与研究:一个自由市场的监管案例


摘要:我们确定了一个基于竞争策略的论点,即当消费者关注点有限的情况下,用于调节复杂或定价复杂的产品的次要特征。有限的关注意味着消费者只能全面地研究少量复杂产品,而无法检查次要特征,因此他们只能表面地浏览更多产品。


通过安全法规,设置某些费用上限或利用其他方法来限制事后对消费者伤害的干预措施,会诱使消费者进行更多或更有意义的浏览,从而增加竞争能力。我们的研究表面,要获得有利于竞争的效果,该法规必须适用于次要特征,而不是针对产品的总价格或价值。作为一个辅助的积极预测,我们认为,与高价值消费者相比,低价值消费者更可能去研究,而不是倾向于浏览。因此,消费者支付的平均价格在低价值消费者的份额中可能会增加。我们还探讨了将研究观点应用于健康保险选择,欧盟不平等合同条款原则,发展中国家的食品安全以及低收入和高收入消费者的购物行为和支付价格方面。


Abstract: We identify a competition-policy-based argument for regulating the secondary features of complex or complexly priced products when consumers have limited attention. Limited attention implies that consumers can only “study” a small number of complex products in full, while—by failing to check secondary features—they can superficially “browse” more. Interventions limiting ex post consumer harm through safety regulations, caps on certain fees, or other methods induce consumers to do more or more meaningful browsing, enhancing competition. We show that for a pro-competitive effect to obtain, the regulation must apply to the secondary features, and not to the total price or value of the product. As an auxiliary positive prediction, we establish that because low-value consumers are often more likely to study—and therefore less likely to browse—than high-value consumers, the average price consumers pay can be increasing in the share of low-value consumers. We discuss applications of our insights to health-insurance choice, the European Union’s principle on unfair contract terms, food safety in developing countries, and the shopping behaviour of (and prices paid by) low-income and high-income consumers.


参考文献:Paul Heidhues, Johannes Johnen, Botond Kőszegi(2021). Browsing versus Studying: A Pro-market Case for Regulation. The Review of Economic Studies,88(2),708-729.


picture from Internet


7、卢旺达暴力的起源


摘要:本文表明,卢旺达过去的暴力活动可以追溯到它最初建立的前殖民国家。在1994年国家组织的种族灭绝大屠杀期间,一个被中央集权统治的村庄相比一个世纪前更是经历了加倍的暴力事件。我们利用邻近尼扬扎的差异来进行工具变量法估计,结果表明这些影响是有因果关系的。在种族灭绝之前,当国家面临叛乱分子袭击时,随着国家存在时间的延长,暴力事件就会减少。我们使用了多个来源的数据,其中包括在一个被抛弃的历史边界上进行实地实验,研究结果表明历史状态的影响主要是通过文化传播的服从规范来维持的。前殖民时期国家的持久影响与政府政策相互作用:在该国发展较早的地方,卢旺达政府动员大规模屠杀时会发生更多的暴力事件,而当政府追求和平时发生的暴力事件则较少。


Abstract: This article shows that the intensity of violence in Rwanda’s recent past can be traced back to the initial establishment of its pre-colonial state. Villages that were brought under centralized rule one century earlier experienced a doubling of violence during the state-organized 1994 genocide. Instrumental variable estimates exploiting differences in the proximity to Nyanza—an early capital—suggest that these effects are causal. Before the genocide, when the state faced rebel attacks, with longer state presence, violence is lower. Using data from several sources, including a lab-in-the-field experiment across an abandoned historical boundary, I show that the effect of the historical state is primarily sustained by culturally transmitted norms of obedience. The persistent effect of the pre-colonial state interacts with government policy: where the state developed earlier, there is more violence when the Rwandan government mobilized for mass killing and less violence when the government pursued peace.


参考文献:Leander Heldring(2021). The Origins of Violence in Rwanda. The Review of Economic Studies,88(2),730-763.



8、非固定时间偏好下的碳税和气候承诺


摘要:我们在一个动态博弈中研究马尔可夫完美均衡,该博弈中代理商具有非恒定的时间偏好,分散的家庭决定总储蓄,而计划者选择气候政策。本文首次使用通用折扣和通用函数形式来解决这一问题。在时间不一致的偏好下,允许计划者选择多个时期气候政策的承诺机制可能是非常有价值的。但是,我们的定量分析结果表明,尽管永久承诺机制非常有价值,但仅100年就可以执行政策的能力会使没有承诺的气候政策的价值增加不到2%。我们通过解析方式求解该模型的对数线性版本,得到了最优碳税的公式,其中戈洛索夫等人的公式作为一个特例。

更重要的是,我们开发了新的算法来数值求解一般的博弈。相对于没有战略互动的情形,凸面损害会导致几代规划者之间实现战略互动,从而使得最优碳税降低45%。


Abstract: We study the Markov perfect equilibrium in a dynamic game where agents have non-constant time preference, decentralized households determine aggregate savings, and a planner chooses climate policy. The article is the first to solve this problem with general discounting and general functional forms. With time-inconsistent preferences, a commitment device that allows a planner to choose climate policy for multiple periods is potentially very valuable. Nevertheless, our quantitative results show that while a permanent commitment device would be very valuable, the ability to commit policy for “only” 100 years adds less than 2% to the value of climate policy without commitment. We solve a log-linear version of the model analytically, generating a formula for the optimal carbon tax that includes the formula in Golosov et al. (2014, Econometrica, 82, 41–88) as a special case. More importantly, we develop new algorithms to solve the general game numerically. Convex damages lead to strategic interactions across generations of planners that lower the optimal carbon tax by 45% relative to the scenario without strategic interactions.



参考文献:Terrence Iverson, Larry Karp(2021). Carbon Taxes and Climate Commitment with Non-constant Time Preference. The Review of Economic Studies,88(2),764-799.



9、向专家传递信号


摘要:我们研究了在信号经济中掌握不同信息购买者的竞争均衡。根据经典的斯宾塞劳动市场信号模型,公司除了观察员工的教育情况外,还可以获得有关员工类型的直接但不完善的信息。公司的排名可以根据其信息的质量,也就是他们的专业知识来定。在均衡状态下,一些高水平的员工放弃信号传递,而被信息更灵通的公司聘用,从而获得正利润。工人的教育决策和公司对其专业知识的使用是战略互补,可以实现帕累托排序中的多重均衡。我们将工资分散和信号传递的程度描述为公司间专业知识分布的函数。我们的模型也可以应用于各种其他信号传递问题,包括证券化,公司财务结构,保险市场或股息政策。


Abstract: We study competitive equilibria in a signalling economy with heterogeneously informed buyers. In terms of the classic Spence (1973, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87, 355—374) model of job market signalling, firms have access to direct but imperfect information about worker types, in addition to observing their education. Firms can be ranked according to the quality of their information, i.e., their expertise. In equilibrium, some high-type workers forgo signalling and are hired by better informed firms, which make positive profits. Workers’ education decisions and firms’ use of their expertise are strategic complements, allowing for multiple equilibria that can be Pareto ranked. We characterize wage dispersion and the extent of signalling as a function of the distribution of expertise among firms. Our model can also be applied to a variety of other signalling problems, including securitization, corporate financial structure, insurance markets, or dividend policy.


参考文献:Pablo Kurlat, Florian Scheuer(2021). Signalling to Experts. The Review of Economic Studies,88(2),800-850.


picture from Internet


10、现实世界中议价的效率:来自二手车批发拍卖的证据


摘要:本研究以实证的方式量化了一个现实世界中存在双面不完全信息议价博弈的效率。Myerson and Satterthwaite(1983)和Williams(1987)推导了在双面信息不确定条件下,双边贸易在理论上的事前效率边界,并证明了该边界并没有达到事后效率,但我们对实际交易中议价的具体效果知之甚少。本研究利用二手车批发行业升序拍卖后的26.5万个交替报价议价博弈序列,并估计或界定了买卖双方价值的分布情况,同时评估了实际议价结果相对于有效结果的位置。研究结果表明,事前和事后的有效结果是接近的,但实际的议价没有达到这两种效果,这表明议价确实是无效的,而这种无效结果不仅是由于Myerson和Satterthwaite(1983)强调的信息约束。从数量上看,调查结果表明有超过一半的议价失败中是存在贸易收益的情况,从而导致效率损失为可利用的贸易收益的12%至23%。


Abstract: This study empirically quantifies the efficiency of a real-world bargaining game with two-sided incomplete information. Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983) and Williams (1987) derived the theoretical ex-ante efficient frontier for bilateral trade under two-sided uncertainty and demonstrated that it falls short of ex-post efficiency, but little is known about how well bargaining performs in practice. Using about 265,000 sequences of a game of alternating-offer bargaining following an ascending auction in the wholesale used-car industry, this study estimates (or bounds) distributions of buyer and seller values and evaluates where realized bargaining outcomes lie relative to efficient outcomes. Results demonstrate that the ex-ante and ex-post efficient outcomes are close to one another, but that the real bargaining falls short of both, suggesting that the bargaining is indeed inefficient but that this inefficiency is not solely due to the information constraints highlighted in Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983). Quantitatively, findings indicate that over one-half of failed negotiations are cases where gains from trade exist, leading an efficiency loss of 12–23% of the available gains from trade.


参考文献:Bradley J Larsen(2021). The Efficiency of Real-World Bargaining: Evidence from Wholesale Used-Auto Auctions. The Review of Economic Studies,88(2),851-882.



11、刑事司法系统的转移


摘要:本文提供了第一个在刑事司法系统中关于流行的、节约成本的转移行为的因果估计,这种干预措施为罪犯提供了第二次避免犯罪记录的机会。我们在得克萨斯州哈里斯县进行了两次自然实验,在实验中首次重罪被告人面临转移可能性突然变化的问题。通过使用行政数据和回归不连续性方法,我们在两个实验中均发现强有力的证据,证据表明刑事司法系统中的转移行为可将再犯罪率降低一半,并在10年内使季度就业率增长近50%。


Abstract: This article provides the first causal estimates on the popular, cost-saving practice of diversion in the criminal justice system, an intervention that provides offenders with a second chance to avoid a criminal record. We exploit two natural experiments in Harris County, Texas where first-time felony defendants faced abrupt changes in the probability of diversion. Using administrative data and regression discontinuity methods, we find robust evidence across both experiments that diversion cuts reoffending rates in half and grows quarterly employment rates by nearly 50% over 10 years. The change in trajectory persists even 20 years out and is concentrated among young black men. An investigation of mechanisms strongly suggests that stigma associated with a felony conviction plays a key role in generating these results. Other possible mechanisms including changes in incarceration, other universal adjustments in policy or practice, and differences in criminal processing are ruled out empirically.


参考文献:Michael Mueller-Smith, Kevin T. Schnepel(2021). Diversion in the Criminal Justice System. The Review of Economic Studies,88(2),883-936.



12、基于似然比检验的马尔可夫体制转换


摘要:马尔可夫体制转换模型在经济学和金融学中非常普遍。尽管对它们有持续的兴趣,但基于似然比检验的渐进分布来测试体制转换情况仍然是未知的。本研究检查了这些测试,并在非线性模型的基础上构建了它们的渐近分布,从而允许多个参数受到机制转换的影响。该分析解决了三个难题:(i)在原假设下无法识别某些多余的参数,(ii)原假设下产生了局部最优,(iii)条件体制概率遵循随机过程,故只能以递归方式表示。解决这些问题可以在与经验相关的环境中获得实质性的权力。这项研究还得出以下结果:(1)关于条件体制概率及其模型参数衍生品的特征,(2)对数似然比的高阶近似,(3)渐近分布的细化,(4)模拟临界值的统一算法。对于在原假设下是线性的模型,算法所需的元素都可以进行解析计算。此外,以上结果解释了为什么某些引导过程可能不一致,以及为什么标准信息准则可能对假设和模型结构敏感。当利用美国季度实际国内生产总值增长率数据进行分析时,这些方法会发现相对有力的证据来支持体制转换规范。最后,我们将这些方法应用于动态随机均衡模型,并得到了与国内生产总值情况相似的结果。


Abstract: Markov regime-switching models are very common in economics and finance. Despite persisting interest in them, the asymptotic distributions of likelihood ratio-based tests for detecting regime switching remain unknown. This study examines such tests and establishes their asymptotic distributions in the context of nonlinear models, allowing multiple parameters to be affected by regime switching. The analysis addresses three difficulties: (i) some nuisance parameters are unidentified under the null hypothesis, (ii) the null hypothesis yields a local optimum, and (iii) the conditional regime probabilities follow stochastic processes that can only be represented recursively. Addressing these issues permits substantial power gains in empirically relevant settings. This study also presents the following results: (1) a characterization of the conditional regime probabilities and their derivatives with respect to the model’s parameters, (2) a high-order approximation to the log-likelihood ratio, (3) a refinement of the asymptotic distribution, and (4) a unified algorithm to simulate the critical values. For models that are linear under the null hypothesis, the elements needed for the algorithm can all be computed analytically. Furthermore, the above results explain why some bootstrap procedures can be inconsistent, and why standard information criteria can be sensitive to the hypothesis and the model structure. When applied to US quarterly real gross domestic product (GDP) growth rate data, the methods detect relatively strong evidence favouring the regime-switching specification. Lastly, we apply the methods in the context of dynamic stochastic equilibrium models and obtain similar results as the GDP case.







请到「今天看啥」查看全文